Specific-factors model
Most undergraduates in their first year in economics have been exposed to an important ingredient in the specific-factors model, a model in which each industry employs some factor used only in that particular industry.What happens to total output when more of a variable factor is added in a production process to a fixed quantity of this specific factor? The answer exemplifies the Law of Diminishing Returns, and this ingredient is basic in the general equilibrium context in which the specific-factors model is set. David Ricardo used this concept when referring to the differential rents that various qualities of land would receive, and Viner (1931) made use of it in his famous article in which he argued with Wong, his draftsman. Haberler (1936) in his classic text on international trade presents verbally some of the logic of what Samuelson (1971) later referred to as the Ricardo-Viner model. The formal exposition of the model in general equilibrium terms was carried out by Samuelson and by Jones (1971), both of whom emphasized the usefulness of the model in the theory of international trade, although the model itself is also applicable to closed economies.
The nature of themodel ismost easily discussed in the context in which only a pair of commodities is produced in competitive conditions, with each commoditymaking use of a factor employed only in that sector (i.e., a specific factor) as well as a factor of production(typically taken to be labor) that is used in both sectors (the mobile factor). In a competitive equilibrium, factor prices and input-output coefficients adjust to maintain full employment of all factors, and with constant returns to scale characterizing production processes, costs of production adjust to equal commodity prices if both commodities are produced. The process of solving the model formally for changes in factor prices and commodity outputs when commodity prices or factor endowments are altered is more simple than that found in the Heckscher-Ohlin model (the standard model used in trade theory since the Stolper-Samuelson article appeared in 1941) in that it is not necessary to solve more than one equation at a time. The key equation is the one that asserts full employment of the mobile factor. With techniques in each sector depending only on the wage rate relative to the commodity price in that sector (the important technological parameter being the elasticity of the demand curve for labor, exhibiting diminishing returns to labor as more is added to a given amount of the specific factor) and each output restricted by the given amount of the specific factor and the intensity of itsuse (which depends onthewage/price ratio), the change in the wage rate is seen to depend on commodity price changes and changes in factor endowments. These relationships are often portrayed in a ‘‘back-to-back’’ diagram, such as figure 1. A pair of (value of) marginal product schedules face each other, each assuming given values for the quantity of the specific factor available in that sector as well as that sector’s commodity price. The intersection point, A, reveals both the equilibrium value of the wage rate and the quantity of labor assigned to each sector.
Details of the solution are found in many places, for example, in the supplement to chapter 5 of the Caves, Frankel, and Jones text (2007). The important results are (1) if either commodity price increases, thewage rate also increases, but by less thanin proportion; (2) any increase in the labor endowment at constant commodity prices drives down the wage rate (to the benefit of both specific factors); and (3) any increase in the endowment of either specific factor lowers that factor’s return, pushing up the nominalwage rate, and thus driving down the return to the other specific factor as well. The asymmetry found in factor returns when the price of a single commodity increases reflects the asymmetry found in the mobility of the two factors: an increase in the price of the first commoditymust lead to amatching increase in average cost. The return to labor is constrained by its use as well in the other sector, one that has not benefited by a price increase, while the return to the specific factor used only in the first sector is not constrained in this fashion. The consequence is that thewage rate cannot increase relatively asmuch as p1, thus pushing up the return to the specific factor employed there by a magnified relative amount so that unit costs increase as much as price. With the nominal wage rate rising, the return to the specific factor in the second sector falls.
An important result in the field of political economy is immediately apparent, even in the twocommodity setting. Suppose the primary issue facing voters before an election iswhether or not to impose a tariff on imports. The specific factor in the importcompeting sector will be strongly in support of the tariff, while the other specific factor would be strongly opposed. This is not surprising. But what of the attitude of voters whose income is in the form of wages? Protection raises the nominal wage rate but also increases the cost of living. Thismay leavemany voters with the desire to stay at home on election day (especially if the weather is inclement) since their real incomes do not depend that heavily on the outcome. (Ruffin and Jones 1977 argue that on balance labor will be mildly against protection in the specific-factorsmodel.) Thiswould help to explain relatively low voter turnout at election times in countries such as the United States. If, instead, the important issue before the voters concerns immigration, both specific factors stand to gain or lose together, and this may result in their joining forces in a political alliance.
The setting of the specific-factors model has two basic interpretations. On the one hand, the two specific factorsmay fundamentally bedifferent say, land and capital (e.g., in Jones 1971). On the other hand, they may represent, say, two kinds of capital that are specific in the short run but can become interchangeable with the passage of time (e.g., in Neary 1978). As Magee (1980) has argued, a sector-specific type of capital might change its attitude toward protection in the long run. The Neary interpretation has become popular in explanations of how the specific-factors model may be linked to the standard Heckscher-Ohlin model, where both factors are intersectorally mobile. Such a link was given a different rationale in themodel of Sanyal and Jones (1982), in which a country produces final commodities by using labor and middle products, that is, goods in process, raw materials, or intermediate goods that can be obtained on world markets. The country may export some of its own production of middle products in exchange for imports that are better suited to its own needs in producing final consumption goods. Thus middle products produced at home with labor and the country’s own specific factors can be traded for middle products requiring, say, specific factors not available at home. In other words, final consumer goods are produced with two mobile factors: labor and traded middle products. (As the Canadian economistDoug Purvis once remarked, in this setting Heckscher- Ohlin does not explain trade, trade explains Heckscher- Ohlin.)
How does the specific-factors model match up with the Heckscher-Ohlin model? In the setting in which only two commodities are produced, differences between the specific-factors model and the Heckscher-Ohlinmodel are often emphasized in the theory of international trade, especially as regards the effects of free trade on a nation’s factor returns. As Samuelson (1948) demonstrated, if endowment differences are relatively small between two countries sharing the same technology and facing the same traded goods prices, factor prices tend to be equalized by trade despite the fact that each factor has a purely nationalmarket. The specific-factorsmodel does not share this property. With the number of factors (3) exceeding the number of produced commodities (2), any tendency for factor returns to become equalized with trade disappears. A related comparison concerns the effects of factors becoming mobile between countries. In the two-factor, two-commodity Heckscher-Ohlin model with countries sharing the same technology and endowments not too dissimilar, a movement of factor(s) from one country to another can be absorbed by a change in the composition of outputs without requiring any change in factor prices. Not so in the specific-factors model with three factors and two commodities, because at given commodity prices changes in factor endowments exercise a direct effect on factor returns. This latter model is often more appreciated by labor economists, who may expect labor immigration to have a depressing effect on national wage rates.
The difference between these two models tends to be less apparent when a specific-factor model with n commodities (and nþ1 factors, only one of which is mobile) is comparedwith the so-called strong form of the n-factor, n-commodity Heckscher-Ohlin model in which the increase of any commodity price serves to raise the return to the factor used relatively intensively in that sector and to lower the returns to all other factors (e.g., see Kemp andWegge 1969). Such a magnification effect of commodity prices on factor returns is shared by the specific-factors model the return to one specific factor is raised, and to all others is lowered. Only the return to mobile labor is not so magnified. Indeed, suppose the mobile factor is not labor, but rather some intermediate good that is produced by all of the ‘‘specific’’ factors. This produced mobile factor model (Jones and Marjit 1991) becomes a Heckscher-Ohlin model that satisfies the strong conditions one real winner and all others losers when a price changes cited earlier.
The case can be made that the specific-factors model with each sector having a unique specific factor but sharing mobile labor with all other sectors is especially useful as a general equilibrium model of production because it does generalize so readily to higher dimensions and has highly appealing qualities: (1) If a single commodity price increases, the output of that commodity also rises, drawing resources (mobile labor) from all other sectors; (2) if the endowment of a specific factor increases (and commodity prices remain constant) not only is its return lowered, but the consequent increase in the wage rate pushes down the returns to all other specific factors. This latter result may yield a surprising consequence the returns to some other specific factors may fall by a greater relative extent than does that of the factor whose endowment has increased.
Although theHeckscher-Ohlinmodelmaynot be especially useful in the many-factor case because extremely detailed structure must be imposed before explicit solutions can be obtained, it does have a distinct advantage in that the two-factor scenario is consistent with a world in which trade takes place in many commodities. There is no two-factor, manycommodity version of the specific-factormodel. The theory of international trade emphasizes that trade encourages each country to specialize in a few activities in which it has the greatest comparative advantage, and the two-factor Heckscher-Ohlinmodel can well illustrate that which commodities a country produces depends both on world commodity prices and local factor endowments. This production choice becomes endogenous it can vary as, say, the country grows and the capital/labor endowment ratio expands. Suppose, however, that a commodity that had been produced in the past now cannot earn ashigh a returnonits capital as some newcommodity on the trading scene. If this capital had become specific, that industry may nonetheless stay in business if its capital can earn anything exceeding scrap value. That is, the specific-factor model may prove useful in modeling why it is that some industries still produce even if they would not be viable if new capital had to be raised for production (Jones 2007).
Some disenchantment with general equilibrium models seems to be based on the widespread difficulty of obtaining comparative static results when an original equilibrium is disturbed by some change in prices or endowments. Detailed structure must be imposed on the model. Sufficient structure is a characteristic of specific-factor models, and further higher-dimensional results can be obtained by employing the following kind of variation on such models. Consider first the way in which a ‘‘bubble’’ diagram can be used to illustrate a three-factor, twocommodity specific factors model in figure 2(a). Each of the two Xi outputs is produced with specific factor Ki and mobile labor, L. Figure 2(b) adds another two sectors, with notations suggesting two countries, with Y-type capitals, KY* andKY, specific both to country and occupation. L* and L are, respectively, foreign and home labor forces, each specific to the country but mobile between sectors, and KX, assumed specifically used in the X industry, is now internationally mobile. This is a five-factor, four-commoditymodel, whose structure has specific factors used only for the ‘‘end’’ products and three types of mobile factors labor in each country mobile between sectors but not internationally and X-type capital,mobile between countries but sectorspecific. It is not difficult to analyze (see Jones 2000, chapter 3) because it can be treated in two stages. In the first, suppose that the allocation of X-type capital between home and foreign industries is kept the same so that figure 2(b) resembles two countries, each of the figure 2(a) type. In world markets suppose the prices of X-type goods increase by the same relative amount and that of Y-type goods stay the same. In each country separately standard specific-factor results are obtained: the return to X-type capital increases relatively more than does the price of X goods, the wage rate rises but by less than X’s commodity price, and the return toY-type capital falls. In the second stage, let X-type capital become mobile internationally. In which direction does it flow? Toward the home country if, and only if, in stage 1, the return to X-type capital at home increases by more than it does abroad.
Such a comparison depends largely, and indirectly, on how much the wage rate is stimulated in each country, and this comparison, in turn, is revealed by the solution for wage changes in the specific-factors model. The formal solution was not derived earlier, but it can be shown (e.g., in Caves, Frankel, and Jones 2007; Jones 2000, chapter 3) to depend on the product of three terms: sX, iX, and yX. sX is the relationshipbetweenthe elasticity of demand for labor (i.e., of themarginal product curve) in theX sector compared to the economy average. If X is ‘‘typical,’’ this has value unity; iX is equal to labor’s distributive share in theXsector relative to its share in the economy and would be greater than unity if and only ifXis relatively labor intensive. Finally, yX is the fraction of the country’s income devoted to the production of X. If the X sector is fairly typical in terms of labor demand elasticity and labor intensity, everything depends on the relative size of the X industry. Suppose this is larger at home than abroad. If so, the wage rate will tend to increase more at home than abroad, and since both countries experience the same price rise forX, the return to capitalwill increase in both countries but tend to increase relativelymore abroad. With a greater increase in the wage rate at home, fewer rents are available to attract capital to the home country.
This two-stage process illustrates how the variation in the specific-factors model that is exemplified for the four-commodity case in figure 2(b) leads to a modeling strategy that makes use of the specificfactor logic at the first stage and then completes the analysis by asking how rates of return to a mobile factor compare in two countries. Jones and Marjit (2003) explore a different interpretation of figure 2(b) in which the two labor forces shown there correspond to a single country’s supply of skilled and unskilled labor. An interesting question might concern the consequences for the wage premium and wage levels of a training program that converts some unskilled labor into skilled labor.
The specific-factors model is a simple form of general equilibrium model in which an extreme asymmetry in factormobility is assumed one factor ismobile and the others are not.Amodel inwhich all factors have partialmobilitywould of course bemore complex, even if attractive for modeling dynamic movements. The Heckscher-Ohlin model also has extreme assumptions namely, that the two factors (in the two-factor case) have the same degree of mobility instantaneously. As all theorists acknowledge, simplicity in model building is a strong virtue unless it rules out features of the setting that are of most concern. As illustrated earlier, departures from the specific-factors setting can often be better understood bymaking use of embedded features that do correspond to the specific-factor model even if other features are also involved. And, as Samuelson and others have often remarked, it is the general equilibrium model that captures much of the basic reasoning about diminishing returns in partial equilibrium settings.
See also comparative advantage; Heckscher-Ohlinmodel; migration, international; political economy of trade policy; trade and wages
FURTHER READING
- Caves, Richard, Jeffrey Frankel, and Ronald W. Jones. 2007. World Trade and Payments. 10th ed. Cambridge, MA: Addison Wesley. A standard textbook used in un dergraduate courses.
- Haberler, Gottfried. 1936. The Theory of International Trade. London: Wm. Hodge. A classic prewar exposi tion of the theory of trade.
- Jones, RonaldW.1971. ‘‘A Three FactorModel in Theory, Trade, and History.’’ In Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth, edited by Jagdish Bhagwati, Ronald Jones, Robert Mundell, and Jaroslav Vanek. Amsterdam: North Holland, chapter 1. Along with Samuelson (1971) the pair of articles setting out the algebraic ex position of the specific factor model.
- . 2000. Globalization and the Theory of Input Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Discusses how interna tional trade theory is altered when some inputs into production have international markets.
- . 2007. ‘‘Specific Factors and Heckscher Ohlin: An Intertemporal Blend.’’ Singapore Economic Review 52: 1 6. Points out how a blend of the two factor, many commodity version of Heckscher Ohlin theory, combined with the (nþ1) by n dimensional specific factors model, provides a simple model of competitive trade allowing both a heavy degree of specialization with trade and a variety of products produced by a given country.
- Jones, Ronald W., and SugataMarjit. 1991. ‘‘The Stolper Samuelson Theorem, the Leamer Triangle, and the ProducedMobile Factor Structure.’’ InTrade,Policy, and International Adjustments, edited by A. Takayama, M. Ohyama, andH.Ohta. San Diego:CA:Academic Press. An exposition of a simple n factor, n commoditymodel.
- . 2003. ‘‘Economic Development, Trade, and Wages.’’ German Economic Review 4: 1 17. An adapta tion of figure 2 to the question of the wage premium between skilled and unskilled workers.
- Kemp, Murray, and Leon Wegge. 1969. ‘‘On the Relation between Commodity Prices and Factor Rewards.’’ In ternational Economic Review 9: 497 513: An extension of the Stolper Samuelson theorem to three factors and three commodities.
- Magee, Stephen. 1980. ‘‘Three Simple Tests of the Stolper Samuelson Theorem.’’ In Issues in International Eco nomics, edited by P.Oppenheimer. London: Oriel Press, 138 53: An argument for the superiority of the specific factors model in explaining supports for commercial policy.
- Neary, J. Peter. 1978. ‘‘Short Run Capital Specificity and the Pure Theory of International Trade.’’ Economic Journal 88: 488 510. Shows howthe passage of time can convert a specific factors setting to the all factors mobile Heckscher Ohlin setting.
- Ricardo, David. 1817. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Reprint, 1981. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Shows both the argument for com parative advantage and the analysis of rents in a specific factor setting.
- Ruffin, Roy, and Ronald W. Jones. 1977. ‘‘Protection and Real Wages: The Neo Classical Ambiguity.’’ Journal of EconomicTheory 14: 337 48. Establishes a presumption that workers would prefer free trade to protection.
- Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. ‘‘International Trade and the Equalisation of Factor Prices.’’ Economic Journal 58: 163 84. The classical argument that factor prices could be equalized between trading countries with different factor endowments.
- . 1971. ‘‘Ohlin Was Right.’’ The Swedish Journal of Economics 73: 365 84. An exposition of the algebra of the specific factor setting.
- Sanyal, Kalyan, and Ronald W. Jones. 1982. ‘‘The Theory of Trade in Middle Products.’’ American Economic Re view 72: 16 31. An analysis of trade that is in the ‘‘middle’’ of the production spectrum.
- Stolper, Wolfgang, and Paul A. Samuelson. 1941. ‘‘Pro tection and Real Wages.’’ Review of Economic Studies 9: 58 73. Shows how, in a Heckscher Ohlin setting, a country would raise real wages if it imposes a tariff on labor intensive imports.
- Viner, Jacob. 1931. ‘‘Cost Curves and Supply Curves.’’ Zeitschrift fu¨r Nationalokonomie 3: 23 46. Reprint, 1953. American Economic Association, Readings in Price Theory. London: Allen and Unwin. A discussion of a firm’s short run and long run average cost curves, with a dispute over geometry.
RONALD W. JONES